Skip to main content

Methods for measuring horizontal equity in health resource allocation: a comparative study

Abstract

There are many existing methodologies on measuring health equity, while seldom has method aiming at health resource allocation. We collected 6 method of measuring equity in health resource allocation. This paper presents key contents of methods on measuring horizontal equity in health service allocation, yet each method has its advantages and disadvantages as well as range of application, which may help researchers or government to make wise decision when choosing appropriate method for measuring equity. Through comparative analysis, we concluded that socioeconomic factors were considered in concentration index; although the Lorenz curve and Gini-coefficient are widely used, which exist uncertainty and incompleteness; overall inequality can be decomposed by Theil index, which is of significance for the planning of urban and rural areas; preferences on a certain class can be set artificially by Atkinson index; it is easy for Chi-square to analyze aided with statistical software; specific regional differences can be calculated by index of dissimilarity.

Classification codes

I1

Introduction

Health resource allocation refers to the health resource which were distributed and flowed among health care industry (or departments), and also influenced by the factors as convenience level for medical service; hierarchy of needs and quantity; the quantity, quality, and scope of supply which could be actually provided by medical and health organization; and effective utilization degree etc. [1],[2].

From the view of [3],[4], the equity in the realm of health resource means the distribution of health resources should be based on the needs as the orientation, rather than depending on the social privilege or income difference; should share the results of social progress, rather than sharing inevitable misfortune and loss of health right [5]. Obviously, equivalent health service can hardly meet the need of every individual, which will lead too little health services utilization coexists with too much. Managing health resources and health care effectively and efficiently is an important part of promoting the development of public health. Experience has shown that, without strategic policies and focused spending mechanisms, the poor and other ordinary people are likely to get left out [6].

The issue of health resource allocation has become more and more concerned to scholars. Almost all scholars agree that equity in health resource is divided into vertical and horizontal dimensions. Horizontal equity refers to the social members who have equal need for health resource receive the same [7]; vertical equity emphasizes individuals with different levels of need can receive appropriately different amounts of health resources ([8]).

There are many methods for measuring health equity or equity first applied in the realm of economy, however, seldom has method aiming at health resource allocation. Under the consideration of simpleness, commonness and easy-comprehension, this paper summarized six methods for horizontal health allocation equity estimation, each method has its advantages and disadvantages, as well as applicable conditions, and been analyzed through definition, calculation method, application, data requirement and other aspect. Meanwhile, different research methods are also likely to produce different results.

Review

Methodology of measuring horizontal equity

In health resource delivery, inequity is means that discrimination for non-need factors, since we determined that only allocation according to need is equitable [9]. An easy method to test for the existence of inequity in health resource allocation is to test whether two (or more) groups (for instance the rich and the poor or different regions) receive the same amount of resource [10]. When we compare whether inequity is present, we need to take into account whether these two groups have the same amount of need (are equal) and therefore whether are completely comparable. This can be amended by correcting for the difference in need between the groups, either via direct or via indirect standardization method. They can be compared, when both groups have equal needs, or when standardized to equal need.

Method of concentration curve and concentration index

Concentration curve

The concentration curve [11],[12], and related concentration index (CI), have now days attained the status of “workhorse” in most health economic studies” [13]. For example, it could be used to assess whether subsidies to the health sector are well targeted towards the poor among countries [14], or whether inequalities in health resource allocation are more pronounced in some countries than in others [15]. And other applications are also possible. When examining the equity of health care resource allocation, it uses the concept of horizontal equity, i.e. treating people with equal need the same and irrespective of their income [16].

The concentration curve plots the cumulative percentage of the health resource variable (y-axis) against the cumulative percentage of the sample, ranked by living standards, beginning with the poorest, and ending with the richest (x-axis) (See Figure 1 below for examples of concentration curve). For example, the concentration curve might show the cumulative percentage of exp. accruing to the poorest p% of the sample. If everyone, irrespective of his living standards, has exactly the same value of the health resource variable, the concentration curve will be a 45°line, running from the bottom left-hand corner to the top right-hand corner. This is known as the line of equality. If, by contrast, the health resource sector variable takes higher(lower) values amongst proper people, the concentration curve will lie above(below) the line of equality. The further the curve is above the line of equality, the more concentrated the health variable is amongst the poor. If the variable takes on smaller values amongst the poor, the concentration curve will lie below the line of equality, and the further below the line of equality, the more concentrated amongst the better off the variable in question is [17].

Figure 1
figure 1

Standardized health resource concentration curve.

Concentration index

The concentration index is an index to investigate the unfair degree of a certain variable associated with social and economic status, which dynamically reflects the effect of the variable influenced by income.

The concentration index is defined with reference to the concentration curve(q.v.), and defined as twice the area between the concentration curve, gexp (Figure 1), and the line of equality (the 45°line running from the bottom-left corner to the top-right). So, in the case where there is no income-related inequality, the concentration index is zero [17]. When computing, firstly, rank by social class with corresponding rank (X); then calculate a certain variable level (H) of one social class level, and according to this variable mean (M), can finally work out CI.

CI = 2 × COV X , H M
(1)
COV X , H = E XH E X E H
(2)

Where, COV(XH) is the covariance of (X) and (H), E (XH) is the mathematical expectation of the product for (X) and (H), E(X) is the mathematical expectation of (X), E(H) is the mathematical expectation of (H).

C lies in range (−1—1). CI < 0, indicates health resource variable is disproportionately concentrated on poor; CI > 0, indicates health resource variable is disproportionately concentrated on rich; C = 0, when distribution in proportionate; the further the CI deviate from 0, the higher level of unfair will be. C = 1, if richest person has the entire health resource variable; C = −1, if poorest person has the entire health resource variable.

Method of Lorenz curve and Gini-coefficient

Lorenz curve

The Lorenz-curve was first developed by Max O. Lorenz in 1905, as a graphical representation of income distribution. In the field of health, Lorenz curve is a way to measure horizontal equity, the x-axis of which represents the cumulative proportion of individuals by level of health resource, ranked in increasing order—that is, beginning with the persons with the least resource and ending with those who are with the most; while the y-axis represents the cumulative total proportion of health resource of relative region (Figure 2). If health resource is equally distributed among individuals, the Lorenz curve is a diagonal line. The more it deviates from the diagonal, the larger the degree of allocation inequality.

Figure 2
figure 2

Lorenz health resource curve.

Gini-coefficient

As a foundation of welfare economics to measure inequity in health resource, the primary measure of income inequality, Gini-coefficient (GINI), has been widely used to test the relationship between inequality and health [18],[19]. A region with no inequality will have a value of 0 while a region with complete inequality will be denoted by a Gini-coefficient of 1. Given a Lorenz-curve plot, we can measure the degree of inequality of the distribution of health resource by a one-dimensional number, the so-called Gini-coefficient ([8]).

The Gini-index, which is twice the area between the Lorenz curve and the equiangular line, which could be calculated as follows (Figure 3).

Figure 3
figure 3

Lorenz curve.

[1] GINI-coefficient = Area A/(Area A + Area B)

The higher the GINI-coefficient is, the more unequal is the resource being distributed across the population in question.

Because 100% is equal to 100/100 = 1, and the two axes in the Lorenz curve goes from 0% to 100%, the area of the entire box must be 1. It follows that Area A + Area B must equal ½.

The Gini-coefficient therefore also can be written as,

[2] Gini-coefficient = (Area A)/(1/2) = 2 × (Area A)

It is the metric you see when Gini-coefficients are shown.

The Gini-coefficient ranges from 0 to 1, with 0 signifying perfect equality (the Lorenz curve coincides with the diagonal line in Figure 3) and with 1 signifying perfect inequality. The standard of Gini-coefficient in health resource allocation refers to income distribution fairness in economics. Gini-coefficient < 0.3, indicates in perfect equity condition; 0.3-0.4, indicates in normal condition; >0.4, indicates in alert condition, >0.6, indicates in highly inequity perilous condition [20].

Theil index

Theil index is first used by Dutch economist H. Theil, who uses the entropy concept to calculate the unfairness of income, TI range from [0, 1], the smaller the TI value is, the more unequal between regions will be. Although the Theil Index (TI) was originally proposed as measures of income inequality [21]-[25], it is now common measures of disparity in health research [26]-[28] and of inequity in health resource allocation, because it is decomposable by groups, and can incorporate group-level data and is particularly effective at paring effects in hierarchical data sets. The formula is as follows;

T = i = 1 n P i log P i Y i
(3)

In formula 3, P i represents the proportion of some place’s population accounts for total population; Y i represents the proportion of health resources owned by some place accounts for the total number of health resources. A weighted sum of inter-unit inequality within each group, called the “within group” component, and a “between-group” component that measures inequality due solely to variations in health resource density across groups. The decomposition formula is;

T = T intra class + T inter class
(4)
T intra class = g = 1 k P g P g
(5)
T inter class = g = 1 k P g log P g Y g
(6)

In the above formulas, ‘Tintra-class’ in this article means the differences of health resource allocation in the area; ‘Tinter-class’ means the differences of health resource allocation between areas; P g represents the proportion of some place’s population accounts for total population; Y g represents the proportion of health resources owned by someplace accounts for the total number of health resources. The contribution rate of the difference between each part on total theil index can be calculated after decomposing the theil index. For health resource allocation, if the TI = 0, means equity in allocation, the smaller the value is, the more equity in allocation will be, and vice versa.

Atkinson index

The Atkinson index is an index used to assess income inequality which was developed by a British economist known as Anthony Barnes Atkinson. The measure is useful in determining which end of the distribution contributed most to the observed inequality [29]. The Atkinson index has a specific feature for the calculation of distribution. The index uses the epsilon parameter to explicitly reveal the inequality aversion of allocation. Epsilon defines how sensitively the Atkinson index should react to inequalities. The Atkinson index is an inequality measure based on health resource allocation, which defines maximum inequality as 1 and maximum equality as 0 [30]. The definition is as follows,

I R = 1 i = 1 n Y i Y ¯ 1 ε f i 1 1 ε , if ε 1
(7)
I R = 1 exp i = 1 n f i log e Y i Y ¯ , if ε = 1
(8)

ε is a parameter related to the external clearer display of regional imbalance, called inequality aversion. The parameter reflects social equal degree for inequality aversion (or preferences). 0 < ϵ < + ∞, the higher the ε is, the display of imbalance will be more obvious, when ε = 2, Atkinson index can reveal moderate imbalance. For assessing equity of health resource, Y i is the health resource gotten by individuals in the ith health resource range (N ranges altogether), f i is the proportion of the population with health resource in the ith range, Y ¯ is the mean health resource in group.

For assessing the equity of health resource allocation, an intuitive interpretation of this index is possible: Atkinson values can be used to calculate the proportion of total health resource that would be required to achieve an equal level of allocation as at present if health resources were perfectly distributed. For example, an Atkinson index value of 0.20 suggests that we achieve the level of allocation with only 1–0.20=80% of health resource. The theoretical range of Atkinson values is 0 to 1, with 0 being a state of equal distribution [31]. The smaller the index is, the more equal the allocation will be, and vise verse.

Chi-square value method

It was statistician Pearson (1857–1936), who first proposed chi-square test (X2 test). As one of the nonparametric tests, X2 test is a significance test to compare the difference of two or more sample rates (or ratio), the theoretical basis of which is Continuous probability distribution (X2 distribution). By comparing two or more frequencies, detecting the difference between the actual frequency and the expectation frequency based on distribution hypothesis in a certain significance level, which reflects whether there exists significant difference between the actual level and theoretical level. The theory is as follows,(1) Computational formula,

X 2 = i = 1 k f i f i ¯ 2 f i ¯
(9)

f i ( i = 1, 2, ,, k) means there are k actual frequencies, which can be gotten through the investigation and experiment; f ¯ i ( i = 1, 2, ,, k ) means there are k expectation frequencies, which should be calculated according to the statistical hypothesis or refer to relevant data.

  1. (2)

    X2 test steps

The specific steps are stated as follows,

  1. 1)

    Establish the null hypothesis H0 and alternative hypothesis H1;

  2. 2)

    Calculate expectation frequency according to the theoretical distribution (or empirical distribution);

  3. 3)

    Calculate sample chi-square value according to the actual frequency and expectation frequency (formula 4);

  4. 4)

    Find corresponding chi-square critical value According to the degree of freedom and significance level a in the chi-square distribution list. If the calculated value is less than chi-square critical value, accept the null hypothesis; otherwise, accept alternative hypothesis.

When calculating, we should check whether variables are completely comparable, which can be amended either via the direct or the indirect standardization method.

  1. (3)

    Evaluation of X2 value on equity of health service allocation

Analyze form the formula, the general term f i f i ¯ f i ¯ 2 (i = 1,2…,k) is a ratio of the square of f i deviated from f i ¯ with f i ¯ , the sum of which reflects the difference between distribution of f i and distribution of f i ¯ . The bigger the chi square value, the more significant difference between distributions will be, and vice versa. Hence, the variation of chi-square value can reflect variable trend of the difference degree between variables’ actual distribution and theoretical distribution. For health resource allocation, if the chi-square value less than critical value, indicates that in a certain significance level α, this kind of health resource is allocated fairly, and vice verse; from the perspective of the variable trend, by comparing a health resource variate in different years, which can also indicates the trend of the equity of health resource allocation.

Index of dissimilarity

Index of Dissimilarity (ID) expresses the extent to which the distribution of the health event studied in the population approximates the situation in which everyone has the same socioeconomic level [32]. In the field of health service allocation, This indicator can be applied to variables related to health resource, such as the number of physicians that would be necessary to redistribute among municipalities to achieve equity (Schneider et al. [33]); ID also can judge whether there are differences in health service allocation between regions, and the degree of differences between regions can be calculated. The definition of ID is as follows;Suppose there are j = 1, 2….k different regions (different socioeconomic levels), index of dissimilarity is;

ID = 1 2 j = 1 k S jh S jp
(10)

S jh means the proportion of a certain variable which can reflect the equity of health resource allocation of jth region (or jth region of a certain socioeconomic level); S jp means the population proportion of jth region (or in a certain socioeconomic level). The greater the differences between S jh and S jp , the higher the health resource inequality degree is. The ID value is between 0 and 1, if the ID = 0, means equity in allocation, the smaller the value is, the more equity in allocation will be, and vice versa. The index of dissimilarity is large, when large parts of the population are in low and high socioeconomic groups and there are few people in intermediate groups [32].

Conclusions

Table 1 summarizes the measures mentioned in this paper and makes some recommendations about the use of the various measures.

Table 1 Summary of health resource allocation equity measures

Each indicator has its merits and demerits and each serves different purposes. The most commonly used measures are concentration curve combined with concentration index and Lorenz curve combined with Gini index, which are easy to calculate; and intuitive reflection could be made with corresponding curve; concentration index can be used to reflect the unequal distribution caused by socioeconomic factors, however, this measure only calculates income-related inequity without considering the other casual variable and not inequity in health service delivery per se [10]. Gini-coefficient allows direct comparison between units with different size of populations, nevertheless, which overlook socioeconomic status [31]. Calculation of Theil index is complex, however, it can avoid the demerits of uncertainty, imperfection, and incomparability when describe Lorenz curve and calculate Gini index; Theil index can also divide the overall fairness, which can better reflect the differences of distribution within and between groups. Atkinson index has an inequality aversion ε, preferences on certain people could be made artificially, and this enables to define how sensitivity the Atkinson index should react to inequalities [35]. Nonetheless Chi-square Value Method is not widely used, it’s convenient to analyze aided by statistical program; which not only can compare the equity condition in different regions, but also can reflect the trend of equity over time. Index of dissimilarity can used to calculate the accurate degree of difference.

Example: measuring the equity of health resource allocation in Chongqing (China)

We illustrate the measures with health resource data in Chongqing (China) from 1998–2012, here we used Gini-index and Thiel index as examples.

Table 2, for calculating the Gini-index of health resource allocation by population, the Gini-index of beds indicates that allocation of beds was in normal condition from 1998 to 2007, while in 2012 turned to perfect equity condition; allocation of doctor was in perfect equity condition from 1998 to 2012; allocation of nurse was in alert condition from 1998 to 2007, but in 2012, the situation was taking a turn for the better. When calculating the Gini-index of health resource allocation by area, Gini-index were >0.5 from 1998 to 2012, which indicate allocation by area is inequitable for a longtime, and allocation of nurse is especially serious.

Table 2 Gini-index of health resource allocation from 1998-2012

Table 3, the trend of theil-index of health resource allocation from 1998–2012 is nearly as same as Gini-index (Table 2). However, theil-index can decompose the overall equality, which can show the contributions to inequality within group and between group components.

Table 3 Theil-index of health resource allocation from 1998-2012

Figure 4 shows that for health resource allocation by population, the contribution rates of the difference between groups are higher than the difference within group, which indicates that the main reason for inequity in health resource allocation comes from the difference between groups. However, Figure 5, for health resource allocation by area, from 1998–2007, the contribution rates of the difference between groups are a bit higher than the difference within group; while in 2012, the contribution rate of both are almost same, which indicates that inequity comes from difference between groups as well as difference within group (we divided Chongqing into 3 groups, the center of Chongqing, southern Chongqing and northern Chongqing). Theil index can divide the overall fairness, which can better reflect the differences of distribution within and between groups, thus provide targeted advice to policy makers or researchers.

Figure 4
figure 4

The contribution rates of difference by population from 1998–2012.

Figure 5
figure 5

The contribution rates of difference by area from 1998–2012.

According to the methods of evaluation on horizontal equity of health resource allocation, as well as the availability of the data, we select most commonly used and appropriate methods to study. Sometimes a single index cannot reflect all the allocation disparity problem, you can construct a comprehensive index, or use one of them as key index, and supported by a number of secondary indices, to more comprehensive, in-depth evaluate the equity of health resource allocation.

References

  1. Culyer AJ: Equity and equality in health and health care. J Health Econ 1993, 12: 431–457. 10.1016/0167-6296(93)90004-X

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  2. KNOX EG: Principles of allocation of health care resources. J Epidemiol Commun Health 1978, 32: 3–9. 10.1136/jech.32.1.3

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  3. Equity of Health Care Service in China. Chinese Primary Care, ᅟ; 2007.

  4. World Health Report. WHO, Geneva; 2001.

  5. Methods for measuring horizontal equity in 515 health resource allocation: a comparative study Health Economics Review 2014, 4: 10. doi:10.1186/s13561–014–0010-x 514 doi:10.1186/s13561-014-0010-x 514 10.1186/s13561-014-0010-x

  6. Diderichsen F: Resource Allocation for Health Equity: Issues and Methods (NNP discussion paper). The World Bank, ᅟ; 2004.

    Google Scholar 

  7. Lairson DR, Hindson P, Hauquitz A: Equity of health care in Australia. Social Science & Medicine 1995, 41: 475–482. 10.1016/0277-9536(94)00352-T

    Article  CAS  Google Scholar 

  8. Kreng VB, Yang C-T: The equality of resource allocation in health care under the national health insurance system in Taiwan. Health Policy 2011, 100(2–3):203–210. 10.1016/j.healthpol.2010.08.003

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  9. Wagstaff A, van Doorslaer E: Equity in Health Care Finance and Delivery. In North Holland Handbook of Health Economics Edited by: Cuyler AJ, Newhouse JP. 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Hoog M v: Measuring Equity in Health Care Delivery: A New Method Based on the Concept of Aristotelian Equality (MSc Thesis 2010–034). ᅟ, ᅟ; 2010.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Kakwani NC, Wagstaff A, Van Doorlsaer E: Socioeconomic inequalities in health: measurement, computation and statistical inference. J Econom 1997, 77(1):87–104. 10.1016/S0304-4076(96)01807-6

    Article  Google Scholar 

  12. Wagstaff A, Paci P, van Doorslaer E: On the measurement of inequalities in health. Soc Sci Med 1991, 33(5):545–557. 10.1016/0277-9536(91)90212-U

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  13. Fleurbaey M, Schokkaert E: Unfair inequalities in health and health care. J Health Econ 2009, 28: 73–90. 10.1016/j.jhealeco.2008.07.016

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  14. van Doorslaer E, Wagstaff A, van der Burg H, Christiansen T, De Graeve D, Duchesne I, Gerdtham UG, Gerfin M, Geurts J, Gross L, Häkkinen U, John J, Klavus J, Leu RE, Nolan B, O’Donnell O, Propper C, Puffer F, Schellhorn M, Sundberg G, Winkelhake O: Equity in the delivery of health care in Europe and the US. J Health Econ 2000, 19(5):553–583. 10.1016/S0167-6296(00)00050-3

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  15. Van Doorslaer E, Wagstaff A, Bleichrodt H, Caonge S, Gerdtham U-G, Gerfin M, Geurts J: Income-related inequalities in health: some international comparisons. J Health Econ 1997, 16: 93–112. 10.1016/S0167-6296(96)00532-2

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  16. Hauquitz A, Hindson P, Lairson DR: Equity of health care in Australia. Soc Sci Med 1995, 41(4):475–482. 10.1016/0277-9536(94)00352-T

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  17. O’Donnell O: Quantitative Techniques for Health Equity Analysis. The World Bank, Washington DC; 2007.

    Google Scholar 

  18. Hsiao WC, Yip W, Chou YJ, Liu YL, Li YC: Evaluation of Taiwan’s National Health Insurance System. Bureau of National Health Insurance, Taiwan; 2003.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Schoen C, Davis K, Des Roches C, Donelan K, Blendon R: Health insurance markets and income inequality: findings from an international health policy survey. Health Policy 2000, 51(2):67–85. 10.1016/S0168-8510(99)00084-6

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  20. Price M: The consequences of health service privatisation for equality and equity in health care in South Africa. Soc Sci Med 1988, 27(7):703–716. 10.1016/0277-9536(87)90330-3

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  21. Conceicao P, Galbraith JK, Bardford P: The Theil index in sequences of nested and hierachical grouping structures: implication for the measurement of inequality through time, with data aggregated at different levels of industrial classification. Eastern Econ J 2001, 27: 491–514.

    Google Scholar 

  22. Firebaugh G: Empirics of world income inequality. Am J Sociol 1999, 104: 1597–1630. 10.1086/210218

    Article  Google Scholar 

  23. Galbraith JK: Inequality, unemployment and growth: new measures for old controversies. J Econ Inequal 2009, 7: 189–206. 10.1007/s10888-008-9083-2

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Biewen M, Jenkins SP: Variance estimation for generalized entropy and Atkinson indices: the complex survey data case. Oxford Bull Econ Stat 2006, 68: 371–383. 10.1111/j.1468-0084.2006.00166.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  25. Theil H: Economics and Information Theory. North Holland Publishing, Amsterdam; 1967.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Harper S, Lynch J, Meersman SC, Breen N, Davis WW, Reichman ME: An overview of methods for monitoring social disparities in cancer with an example using trends in lung cancer incidence by area-socioeconomic position and race-ethnicity. Am J Epidemiol 2008, 167: 889–899. 10.1093/aje/kwn016

    Article  PubMed Central  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  27. Harper S, Lynch J: Methods for Measuring Cancer Disparities: Using Data Relevant to Healthy People 2010 Cancer-Related Objectives. NCI Cancer Surveillance Monograph Series, Number 6. National Cancer Institute, Bethesda, MD; 2005.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Harper S, Lynch J: Measuring Health Inequalities. In Methods in Social Epidemiology. Edited by: Oakes M, Kaufman JS. Jossey Bass, San Fransisco; 2006.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Denavas-Walt C, Proctor BD, Smith JC: Current Population Reports: Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Coverage in the United States: 2010. U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, DC; 2011.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Sen A: On Economic Inequality. Norton, New York; 1973.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  31. Maio FG: Income inequality measures. J Epidemiol Commun Health 2007, 61(10):849–852. 10.1136/jech.2006.052969

    Article  Google Scholar 

  32. Kunt A, Mackenbach J: Measuring socioeconomic inequalities in health. WHO, Regional Office for Europe, Copenhagen; 1997.

    Google Scholar 

  33. Schneider MC, Castillo-Salgado C, Bacallao J, Loyola E, Mujica OJ, Vidaurre M, Roca A: Methods for measuring health inequalities (Part II). Epidemiol Bull/PAHO 2005, 26(1):ᅟ.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Krol A, Miedema JM: Measuring Income Inequality: An Exploratory Review. Region of Waterloo Public Health, ᅟ; 2009.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Schlǒr H, Fischer W, Hake J-F: Holger Schlǒr, Wolfgang Fischer, Jürgen-Friedrich Hake: measuring social welfare, energy and inequality in Germany. Appl Energy 2012, 97: 135–142. 10.1016/j.apenergy.2012.01.036

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Xiaoni Zhong.

Additional information

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Authors’ contributions

YT and XNZ conceived and designed the study. YT made substantial contribution to creation of figures and tables, and drafted the paper. QPZ collected and analyzed data. KH and XNZ revised the draft critically and approved the final version. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Authors’ original submitted files for images

Rights and permissions

Open Access  This article is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License, which permits use, sharing, adaptation, distribution and reproduction in any medium or format, as long as you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons licence, and indicate if changes were made.

The images or other third party material in this article are included in the article’s Creative Commons licence, unless indicated otherwise in a credit line to the material. If material is not included in the article’s Creative Commons licence and your intended use is not permitted by statutory regulation or exceeds the permitted use, you will need to obtain permission directly from the copyright holder.

To view a copy of this licence, visit https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Tao, Y., Henry, K., Zou, Q. et al. Methods for measuring horizontal equity in health resource allocation: a comparative study. Health Econ Rev 4, 10 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1186/s13561-014-0010-x

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/s13561-014-0010-x

Keywords